Paying fishers to release sharks could backfire. Picture by Unspalsh @davidclodePaying fishers to release sharks could backfire. Picture by Unspalsh @davidclode

The Conservation Dilemma

Sharks play a crucial role in maintaining healthy ocean ecosystems, but overfishing has pushed many species toward extinction. In an effort to protect them, some conservation programs have introduced a novel approach: paying fishers to release accidentally caught sharks instead of selling them.

However, a new study published in Science Advances suggests this strategy might have a dangerous loophole—it could encourage fishers to target sharks intentionally, knowing they’ll get paid for "accidental" catches.

How the Payment System Works—And Why It Might Fail

The idea behind "pay-to-release" programs is simple:

  • Fishers who accidentally catch sharks (a common occurrence in longline and gillnet fisheries) receive compensation for releasing them alive.
  • This provides an economic incentive to conserve rather than kill the sharks.

But researchers found a critical flaw—the line between "accidental" and deliberate shark fishing can blur. If fishers realize they can earn money by catching and releasing sharks, they might:

  • Modify fishing techniques to increase shark encounters.
  • Claim that intentional catches were accidental.
  • Prioritize fishing in shark-rich areas, increasing overall shark mortality despite the program.

Evidence from Real-World Fisheries

The study analyzed data from small-scale fisheries in Indonesia, where shark populations have declined sharply due to demand for fins and meat. When compensation programs were introduced, some fishers began:

  • Using bait and gear more likely to attract sharks.
  • Spending more time in shark migration routes.
  • Reporting higher "bycatch" rates—suggesting possible gaming of the system.

“It’s a classic case of perverse incentives,” said one marine biologist involved in the study. “When you attach monetary value to a species, even for conservation, people find ways to exploit it.”

Alternative Solutions for Shark Protection

To avoid these unintended consequences, researchers suggest:

  1. Strengthening Monitoring – Requiring independent verification of accidental catches (e.g., onboard observers or electronic monitoring).
  2. Non-Cash Incentives – Offering gear upgrades or access to premium markets for fishers who reduce bycatch.
  3. Marine Protected Areas (MPAs) – Expanding no-fishing zones in critical shark habitats.
  4. Community-Based Conservation – Engaging local fishers in shark protection efforts rather than relying on payments.

Broader Implications for Conservation

This study highlights a recurring challenge in environmental policy: financial incentives can sometimes distort behavior in unexpected ways. Similar issues have emerged in:

  • Wildlife tourism (feeding animals to attract them for photos).
  • Carbon offset programs (where companies plant monoculture forests that harm biodiversity).
  • Fishery buybacks (where fishers overfish before a program starts to increase their compensation).

The Way Forward

Shark conservation remains urgent, but the findings suggest that well-meaning programs need careful design to avoid backfiring. As one researcher put it:
"We can’t just throw money at the problem. We need smarter policies that align economic incentives with true conservation outcomes."

The study calls for pilot programs to test alternative approaches before scaling up pay-to-release systems—ensuring that shark protection efforts don’t end up doing more harm than good.

(Based on reporting from Science, with additional expert analysis and policy context.)

By Editor